Great Depression in the United States: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
imported>Nick Gardner
Line 14: Line 14:


==The early 1920s==
==The early 1920s==
The condition of the United States  in the 1920s differed markedly from its pre-war condition. The wartime destruction of much of Europe's productive capacity had made it the richest country in the world and Europe's  wartime borrowing had made it the largest creditor. The full convertability  of the dollar into gold under the [[gold standard]] which  had been suspended during the war, was immediately resumed. 


The severest bout of deflation ever experienced in the United States was not during the Great Depression, but a decade earlier in 1920-21 when wholesale prices fell by 56% in a little over a year
The severest bout of deflation ever experienced in the United States was not during the Great Depression, but a decade earlier in 1920-21 when wholesale prices fell by 56% in a little over a year
Line 20: Line 23:




There was nothing unexpected about the later turndown in the economy. On the contrary, a great deal of thought had been put into how to deal with it when it next happened. In 1923, a committee appointed by Herbert Hoover (then Commerce Secretary) had published a 300-page report on the subject <ref name=Hoover>[http://en.citizendium.org/wiki?title=Great_Depression_in_the_United_States&action=edit ''Business Cycles and Unemployment'',  Report and Recommendations of a Committee of the President's Conference on Unemployment, McGraw Hill, 1923]</ref>. The committee had regarded  it as inevitable that every boom would be followed by a slump, and had considered how a future boom could be restrained and how the following downturn could be countered. Among their recommendations were the postponment of commercial and public investment projects and the control of credit expansion by the banks.  Although he endorsed those recommendations at the time, he subsequently proposed severe limits upon the  government's ability to act upon them. He has been quoted as saying - at the depth of the depression - that there should be "...no tampering or inflation of the currency"; that the budget should be "unquestionably balanced, even if further taxation is necessary"; and that "the Government credit [should] be maintained by refusal to exhaust it in the issue of securities" - which John Kenneth Galbraith took to amount to the rejection of the both  fiscal policy and monetary policy actions in face of a depression.   
There was nothing unexpected about the later turndown in the economy. On the contrary, a great deal of thought had been put into how to counter its next occurrence. In 1923, a committee appointed by Herbert Hoover (then Commerce Secretary) had published a 300-page report on the subject <ref name=Hoover>[http://en.citizendium.org/wiki?title=Great_Depression_in_the_United_States&action=edit ''Business Cycles and Unemployment'',  Report and Recommendations of a Committee of the President's Conference on Unemployment, McGraw Hill, 1923]</ref>. The committee had regarded  it as inevitable that every boom would be followed by a slump, and had considered how a future boom could be restrained and how the following downturn could be countered. Among their recommendations were the postponment of commercial and public investment projects and the control of credit expansion by the banks.  Although he endorsed those recommendations at the time, he subsequently proposed severe limits upon the  government's ability to act upon them. He has been quoted as saying - at the depth of the depression - that there should be "...no tampering or inflation of the currency"; that the budget should be "unquestionably balanced, even if further taxation is necessary"; and that "the Government credit [should] be maintained by refusal to exhaust it in the issue of securities" - which John Kenneth Galbraith took to amount to the rejection of the both  fiscal policy and monetary policy actions in face of a depression.   


<ref name=Meltzer>[http://mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae8_1_7.pdf  Allan Meltzer: ''A History Of The Federal Reserve'', Volume I: 1913–51, University Of Chicago Press, 2003]</ref>.
<ref name=Meltzer>[http://mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae8_1_7.pdf  Allan Meltzer: ''A History Of The Federal Reserve'', Volume I: 1913–51, University Of Chicago Press, 2003]</ref>.

Revision as of 09:50, 9 February 2009

This article is developing and not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Timelines [?]
Tutorials [?]
 
This editable Main Article is under development and subject to a disclaimer.


Links and subpages

For an annotated chronology of the main events, see the Timelines subpage;
for an article about events in the United States and elsewhere, see the article on the Great Depression;
for a summary of the relevant economic statistics, see the Tutorials subpage;
for definitions of terms shown in italics see the Glossary.

Overview

The early 1920s

The condition of the United States in the 1920s differed markedly from its pre-war condition. The wartime destruction of much of Europe's productive capacity had made it the richest country in the world and Europe's wartime borrowing had made it the largest creditor. The full convertability of the dollar into gold under the gold standard which had been suspended during the war, was immediately resumed.


The severest bout of deflation ever experienced in the United States was not during the Great Depression, but a decade earlier in 1920-21 when wholesale prices fell by 56% in a little over a year [1]


There was nothing unexpected about the later turndown in the economy. On the contrary, a great deal of thought had been put into how to counter its next occurrence. In 1923, a committee appointed by Herbert Hoover (then Commerce Secretary) had published a 300-page report on the subject [2]. The committee had regarded it as inevitable that every boom would be followed by a slump, and had considered how a future boom could be restrained and how the following downturn could be countered. Among their recommendations were the postponment of commercial and public investment projects and the control of credit expansion by the banks. Although he endorsed those recommendations at the time, he subsequently proposed severe limits upon the government's ability to act upon them. He has been quoted as saying - at the depth of the depression - that there should be "...no tampering or inflation of the currency"; that the budget should be "unquestionably balanced, even if further taxation is necessary"; and that "the Government credit [should] be maintained by refusal to exhaust it in the issue of securities" - which John Kenneth Galbraith took to amount to the rejection of the both fiscal policy and monetary policy actions in face of a depression.

[3].

[4]


[5]

[6]

Boom

Slump

Rescue

References

  1. Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz A Monetary History of the United States 1867-1960 (p. 289), Princeton University Press for NBER, 1963
  2. Business Cycles and Unemployment, Report and Recommendations of a Committee of the President's Conference on Unemployment, McGraw Hill, 1923
  3. Allan Meltzer: A History Of The Federal Reserve, Volume I: 1913–51, University Of Chicago Press, 2003
  4. Peter Temin Did Monetary Forces Cause the Great Depression, W W Norton, 1976
  5. Historical Background and Development of Social Security, Social Security Administration 2008
  6. John Kenneth Galbraith The Great Crash 1929, Penguin Books 1992

Recovery