Supply and demand: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
imported>Nick Gardner
Line 14: Line 14:


===Income===
===Income===
The missing passage in the above quotation from Marshall's Principles of Economics was his "other things being equal" qualification, and the most important of the other things that have to be taken into account is income. The effect of general  rise in  incomes must  obviously be a proportionately equal increase in a community's total spending (unless it increases the  proportion that it saves), implying a community-wide ''income elasticity of demand '' of 1. But within  that weighted-average figure there a great variations among the various categories of product.  It is common experience, for example, that people spend a diminishing proportion on food as their incomes rise, implying a negative income elasticity of demand, an observation that is sometimes referred to as "Engel's Law". There are circumstances in which Engel's law can have significant consequences. In international trade, its effect is a continuing deterioration in the [[terms of trade]] of food-exporting countries with every rise in the prosperity of their customer countries; and the income effect referred to in the previous paragraph can produce an exception to the law of supply and demand that is similar to that of Veblen goods, but for a different reason.  In markets predominated by the extreme poor, most of whose spending is on a basic good such as rice, the income effect of a reduction in its price can lead them to spend less upon it, thus reversing the normal effect of a price reduction. Goods to which this exception  applies are termed ''Giffen goods''.
The missing passage in the above quotation from Marshall's Principles of Economics was his "other things being equal" qualification; and income is one of the other things that have to be taken into account. The effect of a rise in a community's income must  obviously be a proportionately equal increase in its total spending, assuming no change in the  proportion   that it saves. That implies a community-wide ''income elasticity of demand '' of exactly one but, within  that average,  different values pertain to different categories of product.  It is common experience for example, that people spend a diminishing proportion on food as their incomes rise (an observation that is sometimes referred to as "Engel's Law"). There are circumstances in which Engel's law can have significant consequences. In international trade, its effect is a continuing deterioration in the [[terms of trade]] of food-exporting countries with every rise in the prosperity of their customer countries; and in some developing countries the ''income effect'' referred to in the previous paragraph can produce an exception to the law of supply and demand that is similar to that of ''Veblen goods'', but for a different reason.  In markets predominated by people whose income is spent mainly on a basic good such as rice, the ''income effect'' of a reduction in its price can lead them to spend less upon it, thus reversing the normal effect of a price reduction. (Goods to which this exception  applies are termed ''Giffen goods''). Corresponding to Engel's law at the other end of the spectrum, the ''income elasticity of demand'' of luxury goods such as sports cars and jewelery is usually well above one.


===Substitutes and complements===
===Substitutes and complements===

Revision as of 03:04, 28 April 2008

This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Tutorials [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.

Because of their importance to the development of economic theory, an appreciation of the significance of the concepts of supply and demand is essential to the understanding of much of the subject-matter of economics. This article seeks to explain their significance in non-technical terms, as well as introducing the lay reader to some of the associated terminology used by economists and providing a simple introduction to the concepts for students of economics.

Definitions of the terms used in the article that are shown in italics can be found on the Related Articles subpage, and a selection of the diagrams and mathematical equations that are conventionally used for teaching purposes can be found on the Tutorials subpage

Overview: origins and applications

The proposition that prices are determined by supply and demand is so familiar that it seems like a statement of the obvious. In fact, it was not generally known, even to eminent intellectuals such as Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill and David Ricardo, until the idea was popularised by Alfred Marshal towards the end of the nineteenth century [1]. [2] Since then it has become universally accepted that demand rises in response to a reduction in price, that supply rises in response to an increase in price, and that price somehow settles to a level where demand is equal to supply. That proposition has come to be been termed "the law of supply and demand" and is often thought to be as firmly established as the law of gravity. In fact it is what Marshall termed "a statement of a tendency", depending upon particular premises about human behaviour, and falling short of a complete explanation of the market mechanism. It has nevertheless survived in general use as a robust statement that reflects widespread experience. In economics, it has served as a tool that has been used in the construction of other theories and has generated a terminology that has been widely used in discussions among economists.

The determinants of demand

Price

The basic premise concerning demand was stated by Marshall as the proposition that "the larger the amount of a thing that a person has, the less ... will be the price which he will pay for a little more of it" - a proposition that is referred to by economists as the "law of diminishing marginal utility". That premise has implications for the price/demand relationship that are discussed on the Tutorials subpage, but the only implication that is necessary to the operation of the law of supply and demand is that demand rises in response to a reduction in price and vice versa. (Among exceptions to this generally-observed behaviour are goods that people prize just because they are expensive - sometimes referred to as Veblen goods in reference to the economist who coined the phrase "conspicuous consumption".) In principle, an increase (or decrease) in the price charged for a product has two effects upon the demand for it: one is to cause consumers to switch their buying from (or to) it to (or from) other products; and the other is to bring about a reduction (or increase) in consumers' incomes with the consequences described in the following paragraph. Those two consequences of a price change are termed the substitution effect and the income effect. From a supplier's viewpoint, the important characteristic of the relationship between price and demand is the percentage increase of demand for a product that would result from a small percentage reduction in its existing price - a quantity known as the price elasticity of demand for the product, and unlike many of the concepts in the theories of supply and demand, that is an empirically measurable quantity.

Income

The missing passage in the above quotation from Marshall's Principles of Economics was his "other things being equal" qualification; and income is one of the other things that have to be taken into account. The effect of a rise in a community's income must obviously be a proportionately equal increase in its total spending, assuming no change in the proportion that it saves. That implies a community-wide income elasticity of demand of exactly one but, within that average, different values pertain to different categories of product. It is common experience for example, that people spend a diminishing proportion on food as their incomes rise (an observation that is sometimes referred to as "Engel's Law"). There are circumstances in which Engel's law can have significant consequences. In international trade, its effect is a continuing deterioration in the terms of trade of food-exporting countries with every rise in the prosperity of their customer countries; and in some developing countries the income effect referred to in the previous paragraph can produce an exception to the law of supply and demand that is similar to that of Veblen goods, but for a different reason. In markets predominated by people whose income is spent mainly on a basic good such as rice, the income effect of a reduction in its price can lead them to spend less upon it, thus reversing the normal effect of a price reduction. (Goods to which this exception applies are termed Giffen goods). Corresponding to Engel's law at the other end of the spectrum, the income elasticity of demand of luxury goods such as sports cars and jewelery is usually well above one.

Substitutes and complements

The determinants of supply

Market interactions

Equilibrium and disequilibrium

Empirical evidence

References