History of economic thought: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
(Jean-Baptiste Say)
imported>Jeffrey Scott Bernstein
m (fixed 3 periods. (see discussion))
Line 1: Line 1:
{{subpages}}
{{subpages}}


Modern economic thought is generally considered to have originated in the late eighteenth century with the work of [[David Hume]] and [[Adam Smith]], and Adam Smith has come to be regarded as the founder of ''classical economics''. (Earlier approaches are described in the article on the [[History of pre-classical economic thought]]). The  nineteenth and twentieth centuries saw major developments in the methodology and scope of economic theory,  and the process of development continues.
Modern economic thought is generally considered to have originated in the late eighteenth century with the work of [[David Hume]] and [[Adam Smith]], and Adam Smith has come to be regarded as the founder of ''classical economics''. (Earlier approaches are described in the article on the [[History of pre-classical economic thought]].) The  nineteenth and twentieth centuries saw major developments in the methodology and scope of economic theory,  and the process of development continues.


Nineteenth century economists applied deductive reasoning to axioms considered to be self-evident, and to simplifying assumptions which were thought to capture the essential features of economic activity. That methodology yielded concepts such as ''elasticity'' and ''utility'', tools such as ''marginal analysis'', and theorems such as ''the law of comparative costs''. An extension of the relationships governing transactions between consumers and producers was considered to provide all that was necessary to understand the behaviour of the national economy.  
Nineteenth century economists applied deductive reasoning to axioms considered to be self-evident, and to simplifying assumptions which were thought to capture the essential features of economic activity. That methodology yielded concepts such as ''elasticity'' and ''utility'', tools such as ''marginal analysis'', and theorems such as ''the law of comparative costs''. An extension of the relationships governing transactions between consumers and producers was considered to provide all that was necessary to understand the behaviour of the national economy.  
Line 10: Line 10:


==Overview:  categories of economic thought==
==Overview:  categories of economic thought==
Historians  categorise  economic thought into “periods” and “schools”,  and tend to  attribute each  innovation to one  individual.  That is helpful for the purpose of exposition, although the reality has been a story of interwoven intellectual threads,  crossing  some  categories and often persisting  through all of them; and in which advances attributed to particular individuals have often been prompted by the work of others.  For example, the quantity theory of money, that achieved prominence in the  twentieth century and is associated with the name of Milton Friedman, was first  formulated at least  three centuries earlier.  Many of those threads - such as the concept of value and the nature of economic growth - that have  permeated  the categories referred to as "Classical economics" and "Neoclassical economics",  had an earlier origin in  "Pre-classical  economics", which is the subject of a separate article.  (The prefix "classical"  is used to denote the adoption in the late eighteenth century of an approach which was  inspired by the enlightenment  and  the methodology of the physical sciences, and which abandoned previous tendencies to examine the subject in the context of  ethics, religion and politics). Preoccupation with those threads was overshadowed in the twentieth century by the responses of "Keynesianism" and "monetarism" to the problems of unemployment and inflation, but the development of neoclassical economics started before that time and has continued thereafter.  (The boundary between the "classical" and "neoclassical" categories is marked mainly  by  the  rejuvenation  of  the value thread  by  the concept of "utility"  and the associated explanation of price in terms of "supply and demand".)  The introduction - thereby and subsequently - of  new tools of exploration has since led to  the vigorous development of that and  other threads, and  an expansion in the scope of  economics into many  new directions.   
Historians  categorise  economic thought into “periods” and “schools”,  and tend to  attribute each  innovation to one  individual.  That is helpful for the purpose of exposition, although the reality has been a story of interwoven intellectual threads,  crossing  some  categories and often persisting  through all of them; and in which advances attributed to particular individuals have often been prompted by the work of others.  For example, the quantity theory of money, that achieved prominence in the  twentieth century and is associated with the name of Milton Friedman, was first  formulated at least  three centuries earlier.  Many of those threads - such as the concept of value and the nature of economic growth - that have  permeated  the categories referred to as "Classical economics" and "Neoclassical economics",  had an earlier origin in  "Pre-classical  economics", which is the subject of a separate article.  (The prefix "classical"  is used to denote the adoption in the late eighteenth century of an approach which was  inspired by the enlightenment  and  the methodology of the physical sciences, and which abandoned previous tendencies to examine the subject in the context of  ethics, religion and politics.)  Preoccupation with those threads was overshadowed in the twentieth century by the responses of "Keynesianism" and "monetarism" to the problems of unemployment and inflation, but the development of neoclassical economics started before that time and has continued thereafter.  (The boundary between the "classical" and "neoclassical" categories is marked mainly  by  the  rejuvenation  of  the value thread  by  the concept of "utility"  and the associated explanation of price in terms of "supply and demand".)  The introduction - thereby and subsequently - of  new tools of exploration has since led to  the vigorous development of that and  other threads, and  an expansion in the scope of  economics into many  new directions.   




Line 16: Line 16:


===The contribution of David Hume===
===The contribution of David Hume===
The Scottish philosopher, [[David Hume]] was an early exponent of what was later known as [[monetary economics]], and an opponent of "Mercantilism".(That was the term subsequently applied to the then current policy, which was founded upon the belief that a nation's wealth consisted mainly of its gold and silver. Governments accordingly subsidised exports so as to promote inflows of gold and silver, and restricted imports in order to discourage outflows). He contested the mercantilist thesis, partly on the grounds that an inflow of money would cause inflation <ref>[http://socserv2.socsci.mcmaster.ca/~econ/ugcm/3ll3/hume/trade.txt David Hume Essays, Moral and Political, 1742, Vol 2 Of  the Balance of Trade (published by Liberty Fund 1985)]</ref> , but also on the grounds that nations would benefit from the international specialisation that would result from the introduction of free trade. More generally, he argued that all  government intervention in commerce tended to obstruct economic progress.
The Scottish philosopher, [[David Hume]] was an early exponent of what was later known as [[monetary economics]], and an opponent of "Mercantilism". (That was the term subsequently applied to the then current policy, which was founded upon the belief that a nation's wealth consisted mainly of its gold and silver. Governments accordingly subsidised exports so as to promote inflows of gold and silver, and restricted imports in order to discourage outflows.) He contested the mercantilist thesis, partly on the grounds that an inflow of money would cause inflation <ref>[http://socserv2.socsci.mcmaster.ca/~econ/ugcm/3ll3/hume/trade.txt David Hume Essays, Moral and Political, 1742, Vol 2 Of  the Balance of Trade (published by Liberty Fund 1985)]</ref> , but also on the grounds that nations would benefit from the international specialisation that would result from the introduction of free trade. More generally, he argued that all  government intervention in commerce tended to obstruct economic progress.


===The Wealth of Nations===
===The Wealth of Nations===
Line 22: Line 22:


===Jean-Baptiste Say===
===Jean-Baptiste Say===
Jean-Baptiste Say<ref name=SAY2>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/say.htm Jean-Baptiste Say]</ref>. was an influential advocate of Adam Smith's teaching in French government circles, but his best-known contribution was what came to be known as "Say's Law of Markets". Later paraphrased as "supply creates its own demand", it stated that, although there could be an imbalance between the supply and the demand for particular products, no such imbalance could exist for the economy as a whole. Say's Law remained part of mainstream classical economics until it was challenged by John Maynard Keynes. It embodied the (unstated) postulate that all payments for goods are immediately spent on other goods. That postulate reflected the belief that money plays no part in the functioning of the economy, beyond its role as a medium of exchange, because it would be irrational to acquire  money savings and so forfeit  benefits in terms of consumption or investment.   
Jean-Baptiste Say<ref name=SAY2>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/say.htm Jean-Baptiste Say]</ref> was an influential advocate of Adam Smith's teaching in French government circles, but his best-known contribution was what came to be known as "Say's Law of Markets". Later paraphrased as "supply creates its own demand", it stated that, although there could be an imbalance between the supply and the demand for particular products, no such imbalance could exist for the economy as a whole. Say's Law remained part of mainstream classical economics until it was challenged by John Maynard Keynes. It embodied the (unstated) postulate that all payments for goods are immediately spent on other goods. That postulate reflected the belief that money plays no part in the functioning of the economy, beyond its role as a medium of exchange, because it would be irrational to acquire  money savings and so forfeit  benefits in terms of consumption or investment.   
   
   
===Malthus===
===Malthus===

Revision as of 07:27, 22 October 2007

This article has a Citable Version.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Timelines [?]
 
This editable Main Article has an approved citable version (see its Citable Version subpage). While we have done conscientious work, we cannot guarantee that this Main Article, or its citable version, is wholly free of mistakes. By helping to improve this editable Main Article, you will help the process of generating a new, improved citable version.

Modern economic thought is generally considered to have originated in the late eighteenth century with the work of David Hume and Adam Smith, and Adam Smith has come to be regarded as the founder of classical economics. (Earlier approaches are described in the article on the History of pre-classical economic thought.) The nineteenth and twentieth centuries saw major developments in the methodology and scope of economic theory, and the process of development continues.

Nineteenth century economists applied deductive reasoning to axioms considered to be self-evident, and to simplifying assumptions which were thought to capture the essential features of economic activity. That methodology yielded concepts such as elasticity and utility, tools such as marginal analysis, and theorems such as the law of comparative costs. An extension of the relationships governing transactions between consumers and producers was considered to provide all that was necessary to understand the behaviour of the national economy.

The development, in the early 20th century, of systems of economic statistics enabled economists to use inductive reasoning to test theoretical findings against observed economic behaviour, and to develop new theories. Independently of that change, the concept emerged of the national economy as a closed interactive system. Such a system was found to behave in ways that could not be derived by aggregating the behaviour of its components. Analysis of the new concept provided explanations of recessions, unemployment and inflation that were not previously available. The application of empirical data and inductive reasoning to the new concept enabled those theories to be refined, and led to the development of forecasting models that could be used as tools of economic management.

The late 20th and early 21st centuries have seen further theoretical and empirical refinements and significant advances in the techniques of economic management.

Overview: categories of economic thought

Historians categorise economic thought into “periods” and “schools”, and tend to attribute each innovation to one individual. That is helpful for the purpose of exposition, although the reality has been a story of interwoven intellectual threads, crossing some categories and often persisting through all of them; and in which advances attributed to particular individuals have often been prompted by the work of others. For example, the quantity theory of money, that achieved prominence in the twentieth century and is associated with the name of Milton Friedman, was first formulated at least three centuries earlier. Many of those threads - such as the concept of value and the nature of economic growth - that have permeated the categories referred to as "Classical economics" and "Neoclassical economics", had an earlier origin in "Pre-classical economics", which is the subject of a separate article. (The prefix "classical" is used to denote the adoption in the late eighteenth century of an approach which was inspired by the enlightenment and the methodology of the physical sciences, and which abandoned previous tendencies to examine the subject in the context of ethics, religion and politics.) Preoccupation with those threads was overshadowed in the twentieth century by the responses of "Keynesianism" and "monetarism" to the problems of unemployment and inflation, but the development of neoclassical economics started before that time and has continued thereafter. (The boundary between the "classical" and "neoclassical" categories is marked mainly by the rejuvenation of the value thread by the concept of "utility" and the associated explanation of price in terms of "supply and demand".) The introduction - thereby and subsequently - of new tools of exploration has since led to the vigorous development of that and other threads, and an expansion in the scope of economics into many new directions.


Classical Economics

The contribution of David Hume

The Scottish philosopher, David Hume was an early exponent of what was later known as monetary economics, and an opponent of "Mercantilism". (That was the term subsequently applied to the then current policy, which was founded upon the belief that a nation's wealth consisted mainly of its gold and silver. Governments accordingly subsidised exports so as to promote inflows of gold and silver, and restricted imports in order to discourage outflows.) He contested the mercantilist thesis, partly on the grounds that an inflow of money would cause inflation [1] , but also on the grounds that nations would benefit from the international specialisation that would result from the introduction of free trade. More generally, he argued that all government intervention in commerce tended to obstruct economic progress.

The Wealth of Nations

A major advance in the development of economics occurred with the publication in 1776 of Adam Smith's An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of The Wealth of Nations [2]. It was a comprehensive treatment of the subject, using deductive logic in a similar way to its use in the physical sciences. Its main purpose was to recommend changes of economic policy in the interests of economic growth. Adam Smith argued that the division of labour was the main cause of economic growth, and that government intervention in commerce was its main impediment. He advocated government spending upon what are now termed public goods such as defence, law enforcement and the infrastructure, and upon the education of the children of people who could not afford it – and, by implication, upon nothing else. He identified what he considered to be the economic drawbacks of all forms of taxation (except the taxation of land values) and of the deficit financing of public expenditure. He examined the relation of price to value and concluded that the “natural price” of a product was the same as its cost of production, and that divergences from it would eventually be bargained away. Adam Smith is thought to have got many of his ideas from his friend David Hume and from conversations with the French economist, Francois Quesnay (and his fellow "Physiocrats"), but he had a far greater influence upon economic thought.

Jean-Baptiste Say

Jean-Baptiste Say[3] was an influential advocate of Adam Smith's teaching in French government circles, but his best-known contribution was what came to be known as "Say's Law of Markets". Later paraphrased as "supply creates its own demand", it stated that, although there could be an imbalance between the supply and the demand for particular products, no such imbalance could exist for the economy as a whole. Say's Law remained part of mainstream classical economics until it was challenged by John Maynard Keynes. It embodied the (unstated) postulate that all payments for goods are immediately spent on other goods. That postulate reflected the belief that money plays no part in the functioning of the economy, beyond its role as a medium of exchange, because it would be irrational to acquire money savings and so forfeit benefits in terms of consumption or investment.

Malthus

Robert Malthus is best known for his mathematical model of population and resources, which indicated the danger of excessive population growth. In his highly influential Essay on Population (1798) he started with the assumption that populations grow at a geometric rate (2, 4, 8, 16...) while food production (dependent on the supply of land) could only increase arithmetically (1, 2, 3, 4 ....). Eventually geometric growth will overwhelm food supplies and starvation will result. Malthus discusses birth control and delayed marriage, and assumes that advances in agricultural productivity are eventually limited. The model had immediate applicability to biology and became a foundation for Charles Darwin's theory of natural selection. The model continues to play a major role in the making of population policies.

David Ricardo

David Ricardo set the theoretical fundamentals of the classical model. Ricardo's system depended on the idea of the marginal productivity of land, and was the inventor of the "marginal" concept. His idea was that the value of agricultural products (and hence food) was based on the amount of labour required to produce on the least fertile parcel of land. Hence the "Law of diminishing marginal productivity". Landlords owning land that was more fertile, and who could produce more for a given amount of land, obtained "rents". His conclusion was that the future was in buying land. He, of course, did not predict the tremendous increase in technology and productive capacity brought about by the capitalist system.

Ricardo was also responsible for the law of comparative advantage His classic example was between wine and clothing and England and Portugal. Portugal was more efficient than England in producing both cloth and wine, but England had a comparative advantage in cloth production. He showed that it would be advantageous for Portugal to specialize in wine and England to specialize in cloth, and to trade with each other. This resulted in more wine and cloth all around.

Marxism

Karl Marx[4] is the most famous of Ricardo's followers. Writing during the mid-19th century, Karl Marx saw capitalism as an evolutionary phase in economic development. He believed that capitalism was inherently exploitation of the workers, who really produced all wealth, He predicted capitalism would ultimately destroy itself and be succeeded by a socialist system without private property. Marx had little impact on the development of pure economic theory because his theory added little to Ricardo's, though he came to different conclusions. Marx placed little emphasis on the diminishing marginal productivity of land, but more importance on the falling rate of profit. To Marx, capitalist competition would lead to the impoverishment of the "proletariat" or working class and a falling rate of profit. The ultimate resolution would be a communist revolution with the workers seizing power. Soon after the death of Marx, a Marxian school of economics [5] emerged under the leadership of Marx's inner circle of companions and co-writers, notably Friedrich Engels[6] and Karl Kautsky [7].

Other contributions

Keynesian macroeconomics

Monetarism

Neoclassical Economics

The neoclassical approach

Leon Walras

Vilfredo Pareto

Alfred Marshall

John Bates Clark

The Austrian School

Kenneth Arrow

Robert Solow

Robert Lucas

Paul Romer

Other contributors

NOTE: If the above structure is adopted, most of the text below will be transferred into it

Institutional schools

German historicism was represented by Werner Sombart (1863-1941)[8], and historical sociologist Max Weber (1864-1920). In his classic The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism (1905) Weber stressed the importance of Protestant value systems in forming a capitalist mindset and rational outlook toward calculating the future.[9] Vilfredo Pareto (1848-1923) [1] made numerous contributions to the study of inequality, showing that in modern societies wealth distributions are heavily skewed in an exponential manner (so that a few people are very rich rich, and most are poor).[10] In addition Pareto defined "Pareto optimality," which is widely used in welfare economics and game theory. A distribution of wealth is "Pareto optimal" if no one can be made better off without someone else being made worse off. A standard theorem is that a perfectly competitive markets create distributions of wealth that are Pareto optimal.[11]

The most widely read American economist was Thorstein Veblen (1857-1929)[12], a witty commentator on capitalism, the leisure class, and conspicuous consumption. More pedantic but more influential was John R. Commons (1862-1945), who stressed legal frameworks, historical development and practical collection of statistics; he ignored theoretical mathematical models.[13] Commons dominated economics at the University of Wisconsin,[14] where his disciples preached strong government regulation and intervention in the economy, and designed the Social Security pension system that went into effect in 1935. John Kenneth Galbraith was a major spokesman for liberalism and the planned economy, as he poked fun at capitalism and promoted the New Deal Coalition.


The main development of Business Cycle Theory, led by Wesley Clair Mitchell (1874-1948) and sponsored by the National Bureau of Economic Research from the 1920s into the 21st century, used massive amounts of statistical data, but at first avoided macroeconomic theory.[15] Important exponents included two economists who headed the Federal Reserve System, Arthur Burns (1904-1987)[16] and Alan Greenspan (1926- )[17].

Leonid Vitalyevich Kantorovich (1912-1986), and Wassily Leontief (1906-1999) developed the "input-output" technique; it was used mostly in planned and developing economies for determining the levels of resources necessary to produce according to a given plan.[18]

The marginalist revolution

In the 1870s, three economists became responsible for what is called the "Marginalist Revolution" [19] - William Stanley Jevons [20] , Carl Menger [21] and Léon Walras [22] . They, independently of each other, developed a new theory of value based on utility. The three are responsible for the concept of marginal utility [23] , and the derivation of a downward sloping demand curve [24]. The Marginalist Revolution would eventually put an end to the The Classical School [25] and the era of the Neoclassical School [26], which lasts to today, began. This made possible the logical analysis of the "Producers's Decision" [27] or how and why "producer" transforms factors of production into finished goods.


Alfred Marshall dominated economics in Britain from the 1870s well into the 20th century. Among his major contributions to economic theory was his explanation that the price mechanism operates by the interplay of supply and demand, replacing the contention of earlier economists that price is determined by the cost of supply. He was responsible for developing numerous concepts still used in economics, such as elasticity of demand and consumers' surplus, as well as the diagrams used to explain them.

Marshall's work was refined and further developed, and continues to be extended to this day. Neoclassical economists have built magistral logical edifice into a "Production Function" [28] that rival Newtonian mechanics in completeness and rigour. The basis of neo-classical economics is maximisation under constraint, and this constantly involves the "marginal concept" [29]. The tools developed by economists are even now beginning to be used by other social sciences such as anthropology, sociology and even psychology.

International trade theory

Bertil Ohlin, (1899-1979), professor of economics at the Stockholm School of Economics (1929-65) and longtime leader of the Swedish Liberal party shared the 1977 Nobel Prize for economics with British theorist James E. Meade (1907-1995) for their "path-breaking contribution to the theory of international trade and international capital movements."[30]

The Keynesian revolution

Keynesianism, introduced by Cambridge (England) economist John Maynard Keynes in 1936, and revised by John Hicks, dominated mainstream economic thought from 1936 to the early 1970s. Keynes' ideas on the causes of unemployment revolutionized macroeconomic theory and profoundly altered government's involvement in the economy. Instead of micromanagement of prices and factories, the Keynesian model told governments to regulate the overall supply and demand, through taxation and budget deficits or surpluses. In the 1970s economists became increasingly critical of Keynesian ideas, because it could not handle stagflation (the real-life combination of high unemployment and high inflation), and because because of problems with the micro-foundations regarding issues such as the "consumption function." The leading British Keynesians were Sir John Hicks (1904-1989) and Richard Stone (1913-1991)[31] The leading American Keynesians were Alvin Hansen (1887-1975) at Harvard, Paul Samuelson (1915- ) and Franco Modigliani (1918- ) at MIT, and James Tobin (1918-2005) at Yale.[32] Milton Friedman (1912-2006) at the University of Chicago was the leading critic of Keynesianism, though his own alternative theory of monetarism was found wanting in practice.

The monetarist "counterrevolution"

While the Keynesian-Neoclassical synthesis took over the profession, an unregenerate rearguard of neo-classical economists centred at the University of Chicago continued to exist. See Chicago School of Economics They never accepted the possibility of involuntary unemployment or the desirability of government intervention to ensure full employment, and strongly believed in the virtues of markets and laissez-faire. The most famous economist of the Chicago School is Milton Friedman. Originally a Keynesian and a strong supporter of unemployment programs (which employed Friedman and his wife during the Great Depression), he began attacking the consumption function component of the New Deal model in the 1950s. He was mainly responsible for what is known as the Monetarist counterrevolution of the 1970s. In 1968 he announced the Keynesian model was liable to "stagflation" and could not be used to "fine tune" the economy. The prediction proved accurate in the 1970s with the failure of Keynesian models to explain or resolve the "stagflation" of the 1970s, (which combined high unemployment and high inflation), the free market prescriptions of monetarism became a serious alternative. They were espoused by many governments in the 1980s (Reagan in the US, Thatcher in the UK, Mulroney in Canada), and, perhaps more importantly, by the central banks of most industrialized countries. In practice, however, monetarism was too inflexible to set policy and all the central banks stopped using it by the 1990s.

The Chicago School of Microeconomics

The Chicago School of Economics not only challenged established theories in macroeconomics, they pioneered the expansion of microeconomics to include antitrust and many unexpected topics, such as marriage and divorce, criminal behavior, and slavery. The main tool was price theory as developed by Ronald Coase (1910- ), George Stigler (1911-1991) and Gary Becker (1930 - ).[33]


See also

References

  1. David Hume Essays, Moral and Political, 1742, Vol 2 Of the Balance of Trade (published by Liberty Fund 1985)
  2. Adam Smith. The Wealth of the Nations. Modern Library, 2000
  3. Jean-Baptiste Say
  4. Karl Marx
  5. Marxian school of economics]
  6. Friedrich Engels
  7. Karl Kautsky
  8. Jürgen G. Backhaus, ed. Werner Sombart (1863-1941): Social Scientist. (1996), 3 vols.
  9. Stephen Turner, ed., The Cambridge Companion to Weber (2000) excerpt and text search
  10. H. O. A. Wold and P. Whittle, "A Model Explaining the Pareto Distribution of Wealth" Econometrica, Vol. 25, No. 4 (Oct., 1957), pp. 591-595 in JSTOR
  11. Vijay K. Mathur, "How Well Do We Know Pareto Optimality?" Journal of Economic Education22#2 (1991) pp 172-78 online edition. But see also Joseph E. Stiglitz, "Pareto Optimality and Competition," The Journal of Finance, Vol. 36, No. 2, (May, 1981), pp. 235-251 in JSTOR; and Alan T. Peacock and Charles K. Rowley, "Pareto Optimality and the Political Economy of Liberalism" The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 80, No. 3, Part 1 (May - Jun., 1972), pp. 476-490 in JSTOR
  12. John Patrick Diggins, Thorstein Veblen (1999) excerpt and text search
  13. Malcolm Rutherford, "Institutional Economics: Then and Now," The Journal of Economic Perspectives 15#3 (2001), pp. 173-194 in JSTOR
  14. Malcolm Rutherford, "Wisconsin Institutionalism: John R. Commons and his Students." Labor History 47 (2006): 161-188. online edition
  15. Wesley C. Mitchell and Arthur F. Burns, Measuring Business Cycles (1946)
  16. Malcolm Rutherford, "'Who's afraid of Arthur Burns?' the NBER and the foundations Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 27#2 (June 2005) pp 109 - 139
  17. Alan Greenspan, The Age of Turbulence: Adventures in a New World (2007)
  18. Wahid (2002) ch 8, 11
  19. The Marginalist Revolution
  20. William Stanley JEVONS, 1835-1882
  21. Carl MENGER, 1841-1921
  22. Marie Esprit Léon WALRAS (1834-1910)
  23. Marginal Utility Animated graph
  24. Demand Functions and Demand Curves
  25. Classical School
  26. Neoclassical School
  27. "Producers's Decision"
  28. "Production Function"
  29. Marginal Utility and Optimization
  30. Wahid (2002) ch 14-15
  31. Wahid (2002) ch 7, 23
  32. Wahid (2002) ch 4, 20, 24
  33. Wahid (2002) ch 21, 32, 33