Gold standard: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
imported>Nick Gardner
Line 14: Line 14:
  A. M. Kelley (1969</ref><ref>[http://hansard.millbanksystems.com/commons/1811/may/14/report-of-the-bullion-committee ''The Bullion Report'', Hansard 14 May 1811]</ref> whose report recommending the resumption of  convertibility at  £3 17s 10 1/2d an ounce was put into effect in 1821.
  A. M. Kelley (1969</ref><ref>[http://hansard.millbanksystems.com/commons/1811/may/14/report-of-the-bullion-committee ''The Bullion Report'', Hansard 14 May 1811]</ref> whose report recommending the resumption of  convertibility at  £3 17s 10 1/2d an ounce was put into effect in 1821.


The United States dollar had been on an official silver standard since 1785, but, as a result of the setting of an official rate of exchange with silver, unofficially adopted what amounted to a gold standard in 1834 and, after a fierce and protracted controversy, formally adopted the gold standard in 1873. <ref>[http://www.publicbookshelf.com/public_html/The_Great_Republic_By_the_Master_Historians_Vol_III/goldstand_hf.html Hubert Bancroft (ed)  "The Gold Standard in the United States" (excerpt from ''The Great Republic by Master Historians'')]</ref>
The United States dollar had been on an official silver standard since 1785, but, as a result of the setting of an official rate of exchange with silver, unofficially adopted what amounted to a gold standard in 1834 and, after a fierce and protracted controversy, formally adopted a gold standard of $20.67 an ounce in 1873. <ref>[http://www.publicbookshelf.com/public_html/The_Great_Republic_By_the_Master_Historians_Vol_III/goldstand_hf.html Hubert Bancroft (ed)  "The Gold Standard in the United States" (excerpt from ''The Great Republic by Master Historians'')]</ref>(effectively setting the S/£ exchange rate at $4.86 to the £). Germany and France adopted the gold standard in the 1870s, followed by the rest of the industrialised countries by the end of the century.


==The role of the gold standard in the great depression==
==The role of the gold standard in the great depression==

Revision as of 03:56, 30 December 2008

This article is a stub and thus not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Tutorials [?]
 
This editable Main Article is under development and subject to a disclaimer.

The gold standard has long been abandoned, but for a century and a half from 1821 to 1971, the gold standard (with the gold exchange standard) was a significant influence on the economic policies of the industrialised countries, and it was an important factor in the international development of the great depression.

The operation of the gold standard

A country was said to be on the gold standard when its central bank was required to give gold in exchange for any of the country's currency presented to it. The rates at which national currencies were freely convertible into gold determined their exchange rates, and all international debts were settled by the shipment of gold.

In classical economic theory, the maintenance of balance of payments equilibrium under the gold standard was deemed to operate through its influence upon the money supply. A balance of payments surplus would result in an inflow of gold into the reserves of the country's central bank, which would enable it to expand the money supply without risk of not having enough gold to meet possible demands. The increase in the money supply was expected to raise domestic prices, which would tend to reduce the surplus by raising imports and reducing exports. In principle, tbe reverse of those consequences would follow a balance of payment deficit.

The history of the gold standard

Paper currency was in general use before the 17th century, especially for large transactions. When the Bank of England was established in 1694, it made its first loan to the government of the day partly in the form of banknotes which then circulated as means of payment and were held as reserves by other banks. They were generally acceptable on the understanding that they could always be converted into gold or silver at a stipulated rate. In 1717, on the recommendation of Isaac Newton (then Warden of the Mint), the price of an ounce of gold was set at £3 17s 10 1/2d [1]. That mistaken estimate of the relative values of gold and silver resulted in the displacement of silver by gold [2] as the basis for currency valuation, setting an example that was followed by the rest of the world in the course of the following 200 years.

In 1797, however, a panic prompted withdrawals that threatened to exhaust the Bank of England's reserves of gold, and convertibility was suspended [3]. Although intended to be temporary, that suspension lasted for 24 years. The result was an increase in the market price of gold to £4 10s an ounce by 1809 and a depletion of the Bank of England's gold reserves. A letter to a newspaper by the economist David Ricardo expressing concern at "the high price of bullion" [4] led to the setting up of the Bullion Committee [5][6] whose report recommending the resumption of convertibility at £3 17s 10 1/2d an ounce was put into effect in 1821.

The United States dollar had been on an official silver standard since 1785, but, as a result of the setting of an official rate of exchange with silver, unofficially adopted what amounted to a gold standard in 1834 and, after a fierce and protracted controversy, formally adopted a gold standard of $20.67 an ounce in 1873. [7](effectively setting the S/£ exchange rate at $4.86 to the £). Germany and France adopted the gold standard in the 1870s, followed by the rest of the industrialised countries by the end of the century.

The role of the gold standard in the great depression