Financial economics/Tutorials: Difference between revisions
imported>Nick Gardner No edit summary |
imported>Nick Gardner No edit summary |
||
Line 49: | Line 49: | ||
:<math> d_2 = d_1 - \sigma\sqrt{t}</math> | :<math> d_2 = d_1 - \sigma\sqrt{t}</math> | ||
::* No dividends from underlying asset. | |||
::* European exercise terms (so warrants will not be exercised early) | |||
::* Efficient markets | |||
::* No commissions | |||
::* Constant volatility | |||
::* Constant interest rates | |||
::* Returns are lognormally distributed | |||
Revision as of 02:04, 14 March 2008
The Capital Asset Pricing Model
The rate of return, r, from an equity asset is given by
- r = rf β(rm - rf)
'
where
rf is the risk-free rate of return
rm is the equity market rate of return
(and rm - rf is known as the equity risk premium)
and β is the covariance of the asset's return with market's return divided by the variance of the market's return.
(for a proof of this theorem see David Blake Financial Market Analysis page 297 McGraw Hill 1990)
The Arbitrage Pricing Model
The rate of return on the ith asset in a portfolio of n assets, subject to the influences of factors j=1 to k is given by
where
and
- is the weighting multiple for factor
- is the covariance between the return on the ith asset and the jth factor,
- is the variance of the jth factor
Black-Scholes
where
- No dividends from underlying asset.
- European exercise terms (so warrants will not be exercised early)
- Efficient markets
- No commissions
- Constant volatility
- Constant interest rates
- Returns are lognormally distributed
Gambler's ruin
If q is the risk of losing one throw in a win-or-lose winner-takes-all game in which an amount c is repeatedly staked, and k is the amount with which the gambler starts, then the risk, r, of losing it all is given by:
- r = (q/p)(k/c)
where p = (1 - q), and q ≠ 1/2
(for a fuller exposition, see Miller & Starr Executive Decisions and Operations Research Chapter 12, Prentice Hall 1960)