Financial economics/Tutorials

From Citizendium
< Financial economics
Revision as of 08:39, 23 July 2009 by imported>Nick Gardner (→‎Efficient market hypothesis)
Jump to navigation Jump to search
This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Tutorials [?]
Glossary [?]
 
Tutorials relating to the topic of Financial economics.


Financial market hypotheses

Background

Efficient market hypothesis

The efficient markets hypothesis stipulates that all of the available information that is relevant to the price of an asset is already embodied in that price. It is based upon the argument that there is a large body of investors who react immediately (and at no cost to themselves) to any fresh information to buy or sell that asset . For example, if prices are expected to rise tomorrow, investors will buy today and in doing so, cause the price to rise until it is no longer expected to rise further. The question whether stock markets do in fact operate as efficient markets was subsequently explored in studies undertaken and summarised by the economist Eugene Fama[1] [2] and others. Fama concluded that there is no important evidence to suggest that prices do not adjust to publicly available information, and only limited evidence of privileged access to information about prices. It appears that, although some investment analysts may acquire some useful information, most of them do not. A 1967 study of the average performance of managers of mutual funds indicated that they had not been successful enough to pay their brokers’ fees [3], and subsequent studies have reached similar conclusions.

Financial instability hypothesis

[4]

Adaptive market hypothesis

[5]

Financial models

The Capital Asset Pricing Model

The rate of return, r,  from an equity asset is given by

where

rf  is the risk-free rate of return

rm  is the equity market rate of return

(and rrf is known as the equity risk premium)

and β is the covariance of the asset's return with market's return divided by the variance of the market's return.


(for a proof of this theorem see David Blake Financial Market Analysis page 297 McGraw Hill 1990)

The Arbitrage Pricing Model

The rate of return on the ith asset in a portfolio of n assets, subject to the influences of factors j=1 to k is given by


where


and

is the weighting multiple for factor
is the covariance between the return on the ith asset and the jth factor,
is the variance of the jth factor

Black-Scholes option pricing model

The fair price,P, of a call option on a security is given by:

where:

C is the current price of the security;
is the cumulative probability distribution for the standard normal variate from -∞ to ;
X is the exercise price (see options definition);
r is the risk-free interest rate;
t is the time to expiry of the option;
and are given by the equations:


;
;

and

is the standard deviation (or volatility) of the price of the asset.

The first expression, ,   of the equation is the expected benefit from acquiring a stock outright, obtained by multiplying the asset price by the change in the call premium with respect to a change in the underlying asset price. The second expression,  , is the present value of paying the exercise price on the expiration day. The fair market value of the call option is then calculated by taking the difference between these two parts


The underlying assumptions include:

  • Dividend payments are not included;
  • Options cannot be exercise before the stipulated date;
  • Markets are efficient;
  • No commissions are paid;
  • Volatility is constant;
  • The interest rate is constant; and,
  • Returns are log-normally distributed.

Gambler's ruin

If q is the risk of losing one throw in a win-or-lose winner-takes-all game in which an amount c is repeatedly staked, and k is the amount with which the gambler starts, then the risk, r, of losing it all is given by:

r  =  (q/p)(k/c)

where p  =  (1 - q),  and q  ≠  1/2


(for a fuller exposition, see Miller & Starr Executive Decisions and Operations Research Chapter 12, Prentice Hall 1960)

References